In my recent
blogs I have explained why hourly averaging is a very useful method to
assist the least fortunate: it provides an earning subsidy that contains a
strong incentive for people to work more hours.
Perhaps I have assumed that it is obvious why hourly
averaging offers an excellent method to tax the most fortunate at appropriately high rates. Put simply, a lifetime hourly
average is the best feasible and measurable gauge of each person’s economic
fortune. To show why I will describe eight people, who fit into some fairly
simplified but important categories.
Some of the imaginary persons find it easy to do well in the
job market. They might earn more because of their natural talents, their connections,
or simple good luck. Others, however, are unable to earn high wages because
they have not benefited from such good luck. Another dimension of luck is that
of family background, people can either come from a rich family which offers
them support or a poor family which is unable to assist them in ways that will
generate more income and wealth.
All of these people freely choose (with no mitigating
factors) to work full or part-time. If we look at some index of their income
and wealth against which to tax them we would classify people as follows:
Person
|
Low
or High wage?
|
Part-time
worker or full-time
|
Rich/Poor
family
|
Income/wealth
|
Adrianne
|
L
|
PT
|
Poor
|
Very
Low
|
Brenda
|
L
|
FT
|
Poor
|
Low
|
Celine
|
H
|
PT
|
Poor
|
Low
|
Daphne
|
H
|
FT
|
Poor
|
Fairly High
|
Edith
|
L
|
PT
|
Rich
|
Middling
|
Fran
|
L
|
FT
|
Rich
|
Fairly High
|
Gina
|
H
|
PT
|
Rich
|
Fairly
High
|
Hannah
|
H
|
FT
|
Rich
|
Very high
|
Table 1 : Fortune and work choice of 8 people
People’s income/wealth generally goes up as we move down the
table and those at the bottom of the table are also more fortunate. A
progressive tax system (which could capture returns to fortune from family
transfers, investment income and earned income) would therefore tax Hannah more
than Adrianne, which is the right sort of outcome.
However, taxing income and wealth does not capture the
difference between all of the individuals. If we place people on a numeric
scale for both their income/wealth rating and the areas in which they have good
fortune we can see that in most cases there is a difference (see table 2). This
difference tracks their decision to work full or part-time. There is nothing
wrong with people making this choice of course. However, the choice does not
indicate how economically fortunate they are – they just want to work fewer
hours (for example because they want to spend more time on their hobbies).
One way to put the problem is that income and wealth can
vary due to numerous factors including the choices that people make. Some of
these factors will be examples of fortune, but income and wealth are influenced
by other factors as well. The important factor here is the amount of time they
work, though another factor could be their tendency to spend or save. This
would also influence their level of wealth and investment income, and is reason
to be cautious about taxing wealth, as I discussed in a previous
blog.
Person
|
Income/wealth
|
Fortune
in family or job
|
Difference
between the two?
|
Adrianne
|
Very
Low
|
Low
|
Y
|
Brenda
|
Low
|
Low
|
N
|
Celine
|
Low
|
Middling
|
Y
|
Daphne
|
Fairly High
|
Middling
|
Y
|
Edith
|
Middling
|
Middling
|
N
|
Fran
|
Fairly High
|
Middling
|
Y
|
Gina
|
Fairly
High
|
High
|
Y
|
Hannah
|
Very high
|
High
|
N
|
Table 2 : Problem with tracking fortune on the basis of
income and wealth
For progressive taxation on income that tracks fortune, there
is a problem. Some full-time workers are taxed at higher rates than their
fortune-level would appear to warrant (Fran, Brenda and Daphne) while the
part-time workers are taxed at lower rates than their relative fortune level (Celine
and Gina). If taxes were made less progressive then less tax revenue would be
generated overall, leaving less revenue to assist people like Adrianne and
Brenda.
The dilemma continues as well because while higher tax-rates
might generate more revenues, they might encourage quite a lot of people to
reduce their hours. It might encourage the Daphnes of this world to become like
Celines, Frans to be like Ediths and Hannahs to be like Ginas. If people reduce
their hours then everyone suffers as a) there are less goods and services
available and those that remain will probably be more expensive (prices will
rise) and b) there will be smaller tax revenues available to assist the less economically
fortunate (particularly when we remember that tax revenues are required for important
issues such as administering law, policing, democratic institutions, development,
and for providing education, healthcare, support for the disabled and national defence).
Calculating taxation using a lifetime
hourly average income enables us to much better tax people in accordance
with their economic fortune. As table 3 shows, lifetime hourly average will
coincide much better with good fortune.
Person
|
Income/wealth
|
Fortune
in family or job
|
Difference
between the two?
|
Lifetime
Hourly Average Income
|
Adrianne
|
Very
Low
|
Low
|
Y
|
Very Low
|
Brenda
|
Low
|
Low
|
N
|
Very Low
|
Celine
|
Low
|
Middling
|
Y
|
Middling
|
Daphne
|
Fairly High
|
Middling
|
Y
|
Low
|
Edith
|
Middling
|
Middling
|
N
|
High
|
Fran
|
Fairly High
|
Middling
|
Y
|
Middling
|
Gina
|
Fairly
High
|
High
|
Y
|
Extremely
High
|
Hannah
|
Very high
|
High
|
N
|
Very High
|
Table 3 : Lifetime Hourly Average for the eight people
Indeed, lifetime hourly averaging is potentially quite nuanced,
and this points to the other major advantage of the system. Taxing people on an
hourly basis means that the tax system gives people a strong incentive to work
full-time rather than part-time. Adrianne will have a strong tax incentive to work
longer like Brenda, Celine like Daphne, Edith like Fran and Gina to do like
Hannah. It therefore has the opposite effect to all other tax proposals—instead
of reducing the incentive to work this tax system would decrease it. This means
that the economy will provide more goods and services (and therefore cheaper
prices for these) than we would expect for any other highly progressive tax
system.
We want to tax the most economically fortunate without
discouraging economically productive activity and lifetime hourly averaging
offers the best available means to do so.
No comments:
Post a Comment