My proposal for a Comprehensive Acquired Income tax-base takes elements
of Comprehensive Income (or Accretion, or Schanz-Haig-Simons) taxation and also
elements of Consumption taxation.
The idea is to record the market value of the resources
that people receive from their society, at the time at which the person
receives them. This means that if someone receives some money, goods or
services from another party (whether it be their employer, a return on an
investment, or a gift from another person) at a particular time the assumption
should be that this would count as gross income and be liable for tax.
As it is designed be applied on a lifetime basis, my
Comprehensive Acquired base removes the most controversial requirement of the
Accretion approach. This is that everyone’s property should be valued every
year in order to find out how much it has changed in value. This would be a
very difficult, and no doubt controversial, annual undertaking, and few people
propose applying this traditional ideal in the real world. Furthermore, people
may not have the liquid assets to pay the tax liability on property they own
which has increased in value. The Accretion approach therefore shares this
controversial aspect with proposals to tax people on the total value of their property;
the wealth tax.
Removing the focus on the annual change in wealth as part
of the tax calculation raises the question of when the tax is applied. The
simple answer is that gains are taxed when they are realised. When someone receives money from their employer or sells
something they own for a profit this would then count as part of their lifetime
taxable income. This lifetime tally would therefore increase as time goes on,
and lifetime averaging proposals such as mine allow the denominator by which to
divide this lifetime total to increase as well.
It is possible within this approach to allow the deferral
of taxation on certain forms of gains, for example investment gains. The idea
is that certain types of income could be ring-fenced
such that any gains that remain within the ring-fence remain untaxed. It is
only when people switch resources from these special categories to a form which
can be used for consumption (such as a current account) then the lifetime gains
on such ring-fenced investments can be accounted. Once the total gain exceeds
the total invested then these profits can count as lifetime income. In many
cases this profit will occur when the taxpayer dies and their property is
valued/constructively realized prior to disbursal. Financial investments and
company ownership are the obvious candidates for such treatment, but a primary
residence is another potential category.
I have described my proposal at various points as an
‘income’ tax base and as a hybrid with consumption taxation, which needs to be
explained. If the state were only to tax financial income this might encourage
employers and benefactors to provide resources in the form of services instead
of financial income. In order to close this loophole, it is therefore necessary
to insist that the market value of goods and services that have been paid for
by others should also be included in someone’s lifetime tax calculation.
Clearly the presentation provided above is a relatively
simple one and there are more difficult issues and exceptions to take account
of. For example, I would argue that certain forms of income should be excluded,
such as small non-financial gifts. These gifts, as long as their cumulative
value is small, are not resource-transfers but rather tokens of affection which
need not be taxed. However, I will have to point readers towards Chapter 4 of
Rethinking Taxation for a fuller discussion of my tax base and potential
exceptions to the principle that the market value of all income should count as
taxable.
No comments:
Post a Comment